Journal of Applied Science and Engineering

Published by Tamkang University Press

1.30

Impact Factor

1.60

CiteScore

Earl-Juei Wang1

1Department of Industrial Management National Pingtung University of Science and Technology Pingtung, Taiwan 912, R.O.C.


 

Received: October 14, 1999
Accepted: December 12, 1999
Publication Date: December 12, 1999

Download Citation: ||https://doi.org/10.6180/jase.1999.2.4.02  


ABSTRACT


Efforts to reduce levels of sulfur dioxide (SO2) are increasingly emphasized as an effective response to dire environmental circumstances worldwide. In light of the vast number of environmental uncertainties, a utility must analyze the nexus of different alternatives from a broader and long-term perspective with various implications. While attempting to comply with environmental provisions and satisfying privatization trends in the electric industry, this work presents a novel model which includes alternatives such as switching fuels, installing scrubbers, purchasing emission credits, and procuring power for thermal plants. Data from Taiwan’s utility scheme are used to analyze the effectiveness of the proposed model. Implementation results demonstrate that purchasing credits or procuring power from independent power producers (IPPs) is more beneficial than other alternatives. By using the proposed model, Taipower will be able to evaluate the effect of the newly issues and the governments could review the related regulations.


Keywords: Sulfur dioxide, Economic instrument, Mixed integer programming, Thermal plants, Environmental provisions


REFERENCES


  1. [1] Bernstein, M., Farrell, A., and Winebrake, J., "The environment and economics: the impact of restricting the SO2 allowance market. ," Energy Policy, Vol.22, No.9, pp. 748-754 (1994).
  2. [2] Coggins, J.S. and Swinton, J.R., The price of pollution: a dual approach to valuing SO2 allowances. "Environmental Economics" and "Management 30", pp. 58-72 (1996).
  3. [3] Conrad, K. and Kohn, R.E., "The US market for SO2 permits.," Energy Policy, Vol.24, No.12, pp.1051-1059 (1996).
  4. [4] Curlee, T.R., "Historical responses to environmental externalities in electric power" Energy Policy, pp. 926-936, Sept. (1993).
  5. [5] Dales, J., Pollution property and prices. University Press of Toronto. (1968).
  6. [6] "Energy Commission MOEA," Application Instructions of New Generations. (1995).
  7. [7] Fullerton, D., McDermott, S.P., and Caulkins, J.P.,. "Sulfur dioxide compliance of a regulated utility," Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 34, pp. 32-53 (1997).
  8. [8] Halkos, G.E., "Sulphur abatement policy: implications of cost differentials," Energy Policy, pp. 1035-1043.l (1993).
  9. [9] Hsu, George J.Y. and Chen, T.Y., "The reform of the electric power industry in Taiwan," Energy Policy 25(11), pp. 951-957 (1997).
  10. [10] Jackson, T., “Joint implementation and cost-effectiveness under the Framework Convention on Climate Change,” Energy Policy, Vol.23, No.2, pp. 117-138 (1995).
  11. [11] Montgomery, D.W. "Markets in licenses and efficient pollution control programs", Journal of Economic Theory, 5, pp. 395-418 (1972).
  12. [12] Palmer, K. and Burtraw, D. "Electricity restructuring and regional air pollution," Resource and Energy Economics 19, pp. 139-174 (1997).
  13. [13] Tolley, G.S., Griffes, P.H., Chirinko, R.S., Geddes, R.R., and Bodmer, E., "Emerging issues in the regulation of electric utilities," Resources and Energy 14, pp. 3-35 (1992).
  14. [14] Wang, E.J., Jaraiedi, M., and Torries, T.F., "Modeling long-run Cost minimization and environmental provisions for utility expansion," Energy Economics 18, pp. 49-68 (1996).